Misplaced Pages

Sanzu River

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.

The Sanzu-no-Kawa ( 三途の川 , "Sanzu River", literally the "Three-World River" in reference to Buddhist ideas about realms of existence) is a mythological river in Japanese Buddhist tradition similar to the Chinese concept of Huang Quan (Yellow Springs) , Indian concept of the Vaitarani and Greek concept of the Styx .

#268731

53-464: Before reaching the afterlife, the souls of the deceased must cross the river by one of three crossing points: a bridge, a ford, or a stretch of deep, snake-infested waters. The weight of one's offenses while alive determines which path an individual must take. It is believed that a toll of six mon must be paid before a soul can cross the river, a belief reflected in Japanese funerals when the necessary fee

106-492: A Kami / Bodhisattva who helps the souls of children who died too early to avoid the attentions of the Oni and of Shozuka-no-Baba and Datsueba . This Buddhist mythology-related article is a stub . You can help Misplaced Pages by expanding it . This article relating to Japanese mythology is a stub . You can help Misplaced Pages by expanding it . This article related to a river in Japan

159-630: A floor price for a store of value, still less to re-price everything and rewrite all accounts to a unit of account (the most stable function). Thus it tends to be the medium of exchange function that constrains what can be used as a form of financial capital . It was once common in the United States to widely accept a check ( British English : cheque ) as a medium of exchange, several parties endorsing it perhaps multiple times before it would eventually be deposited for its value in units of account, and thus redeemed. This practice became less common as it

212-489: A coin with a face value of 100 mon) was valued at only 8 rin (0.8 sen) in that sen period. Though the production of copper, silver, and gold coins had already started in the eighth century, they were not often used as a medium for exchange until later when the Japanese started importing Chinese coins, which replaced the Japanese commodity currency economy. As internal trade grew due to agricultural and handicraft developments,

265-576: A face value of 10 mon (but contained 3 times as much copper as a 1 mon Kan’ei Tsūhō coin), which lead to the coin being discontinued very shortly after it started circulating as it was not accepted for its nominal value. However, in 1835 (during the Bakumatsu ) the Tokugawa shogunate tried issuing a larger denomination copper coin again with the Tenpō Tsūhō 100 mon coin which this time only contained five and

318-532: A half times the amount of copper in a 1 mon coin, but was accepted nonetheless. The introduction of this denomination caused large scale inflation comparable to that of caused by the 100 wén coin minted by the Qing dynasty in 1853, or the 100 mun coin issued by the Kingdom of Joseon in 1866. The reason for the change in mentality was the scarcity of copper which had earlier forced the Japanese to mint iron coins breaking

371-546: A measurable value of exchange. The market measures or sets the real value of various goods and services using the medium of exchange as a unit of measure i.e., standard or the yard stick of measurement of wealth. There is no other alternative to the mechanism used by the market to set, determine, or measure the value of various goods and services. Determination of price is an essential condition for justice in exchange, efficient allocation of resources, economic growth, welfare and justice. The most important and essential function of

424-402: A medium of exchange is to be widely acceptable and have relatively stable purchasing power (real value). The following characteristics are essential: To serve as a measure of value, a medium of exchange requires constant inherent value of its own or must be firmly linked to a definite basket of goods and services. Furthermore, constant intrinsic value and stable purchasing power are needed. Gold

477-429: A row, discount given was 4 mon, so 96 stringed coins of 1 mon were accepted at par with 100 mon. Similar discounts existed probably for other bulk payments with small coinage in stringed form. During the history of the Japanese mon, many coins with different inscriptions were cast. The main coins cast by the central government were: Many Japanese domains produced their own currency, which happened chaotically, so that

530-415: A sen). So while not all mon were valued equally, their metal kind counted after the transition to decimal sen: bronze was valued more highly than copper. The first physical rin denomination was introduced in 1873 with the 1 rin coin (with the 5 rin coin introduced in 1916), as until that time the rin had existed only as an accounting unit (10 rin = 1 sen). The most current coin, the Tenpō Tsūhō ( 天保通寶 ,

583-415: A thing". In a barter transaction, one valuable good is exchanged for another of approximately equivalent value. William Stanley Jevons described how a widely accepted medium allows each barter exchange to be split into three difficulties of barter. A medium of exchange is deemed to eliminate the need for a coincidence of wants . A barter exchange requires each party to a transaction to have something

SECTION 10

#1732901828269

636-812: Is a stub . You can help Misplaced Pages by expanding it . Japanese mon (currency) The mon ( 文 ) was the currency of Japan from the Muromachi period in 1336 until the early Meiji period in 1870. It co-circulated with the new sen until 1891. Throughout Japanese history, there were many styles of currency of many shapes, styles, designs, sizes and materials, including gold , silver , bronze , etc. The kanji for mon ( 文 ) also shares its name with Chinese wén , Korean mun , Vietnamese văn . Coins denominated in mon were cast in copper or iron and circulated alongside silver and gold ingots denominated in shu , bu and ryō , with 4000 mon = 16 shu = 4 bu = 1 ryō. In 1869, due to depreciation against gold,

689-402: Is artificially overvalued by law will drive out of circulation a currency that is artificially undervalued by that law." Gresham's law is a specific application of the general law of price controls. A common explanation is that people will always keep the less adultered, less clipped, less filed, less trimmed coin, and offer the other in the marketplace for the full units for which it is marked. It

742-421: Is assumed by economists, such as William Stanley Jevons, to have arisen in antiquity as awareness grew of the limitations of barter . The form of the "medium of exchange" follows that of a token, which has been further refined as money . A "medium of exchange" is considered one of the functions of money . The exchange acts as an intermediary instrument as the use can be to acquire any good or service and avoids

795-477: Is because a store of value can become more valuable if it is scarce in the marketplace. When the medium of exchange is scarce, traders will pay to rent it ( interest ), which acts as an impedance to trade. In stable or deflationary environments, interest is a net transfer of wealth from debtor to creditor with the opposite transfer under inflationary environments. Fiat currencies function as money with "no intrinsic value" but rather exchange values which facilitate

848-409: Is in denominations of that unit, making accounting simpler to perform, it is more often the case that media of exchange have no natural relationship to that unit, and must be 'minted' as having that value. Further, there may be variances in quality of the underlying good which may not have fully agreed perceived value grading. The difference between the two functions becomes obvious when one considers

901-471: Is inevitably the bad coins proffered, good ones retained. Banks as financial intermediaries between ultimate savers and borrowers, and their ability to generate a medium of exchange marked higher than a fiat currency's store of value, is the basis of banking . Central banking is based on the principle that no medium requires more than the guarantee of the state that it can be redeemed for payment of debt as " legal tender " – so all money equally backed by

954-479: Is not a unit or standard measure of wealth and so the manipulation impedes the market mechanism by setting or determining just prices. This leads to a situation where no value-related economic data is just or reliable. On the other hand, Chartalists claim that the ability to manipulate the value of fiat money is an advantage, in that fiscal stimulus is more easily available in times of economic crisis. Because fiat money has "no intrinsic value," when two parties use

1007-410: Is not exchange of goods for some universal commodity, but an exchange for credit. He argues that "credit and credit alone is money". Anthropologist Caroline Humphrey examines the available ethnographic data and concludes that "No example of a barter economy, pure and simple, has ever been described, let alone the emergence from it of money; all available ethnography suggests that there never has been such

1060-618: Is placed in the casket with the dead. The Sanzu River is popularly believed to be in Mount Osore , a suitably desolate and remote part of Aomori Prefecture in northern Japan. Similarly to the Sanzu-no-Kawa , there is also the Sai no Kawara ( 賽の河原 , "River-plain of the Dead") , a boundary by which the souls of children who died too early cross over to the realm of the Dead, with the help of Jizō ,

1113-606: Is why they were escribed with Song dynasty inscriptions as coins from the Song dynasty were already circulating in Southeast Asia and the populace had already become accustomed to them. The trade of mon coins stopped however after the Shogunate banned the export of copper in 1715. In 1708 the Tokugawa shogunate introduced the Hōei Tsūhō ( Kyūjitai : 寳永通寳 ; Shinjitai : 宝永通宝 ) which had

SECTION 20

#1732901828269

1166-555: The Shichūsen  [ ja ] coinage produced in Japan by the nobility and private local mints, and not by the imperial government or before the establishment of the Tokugawa shogunate which were often poor in appearance, as well as damaged and worn out imported Chinese coins . In 1636, the Kan'ei Tsūhō ( Kyūjitai : 寛永通寳 ; Shinjitai : 寛永通宝) coin was introduced by the government of

1219-627: The Dutch East India Company and Chinese merchant ships from Southeast Asia . The Japanese merchants who were now prohibited from exporting mon coins directly to Vietnam used the Dutch traders as middlemen and exported, between 1633 and 1637, around 105,835 strings of 960 Eiraku Tsūhō and Kan’ei Tsūhō coins (or 101,600,640 mon) to Vietnam. From 1659 this continued with the Nagasaki trade coins which were specifically minted for foreign markets; this

1272-521: The Ming dynasty , which they referred to as Toraisen ( 渡来銭 ) or Minsen ( 明 銭 ), but the high demand for copper coinage inspired local and private production of copper coins ( Shichūsen , 私 鋳 銭 ). An example of a Shichūsen used for trade with China and the Ryukyu Kingdom would be a Kōbu Tsūhō coin minted by Satsuma domain which included the character " 治 " ( Ji ) on the reverse indicating that it

1325-465: The Vietnamese market where a huge influx of Eiraku Tsūhō and Kan'ei Tsūhō coins from Japan made the Japanese mon the de facto currency of the region. The large export of Japanese coins to Vietnam during this period mostly happened on Red seal ships . From 1633 the Tokugawa government adopted the isolationist Sakoku policy. The Shogunate, however, opened up the seaport of Nagasaki to export with

1378-522: The isolationist policies of the Tokugawa shogunate, the outflow of currency halted and Kan'ei Tsūhō coins would continue to stay the main coin circulating in Japan. Kan'ei Tsūhō were minted for 230 years despite the fact that the Kan’ei era ended in 1643, and coins would continue to bear the Kan’ei legend, even when a new denomination of the coin was introduced a century later, though they were not all uniform as

1431-401: The limitations of barter ; where what one wants has to be matched with what the other has to offer. However, there is little evidence of a pre-monetary society in which barter is the primary mode of exchange; instead, such societies operated largely along the principles of gift economy and debt . In his book Debt: The First 5,000 Years , anthropologist David Graeber argues against

1484-595: The 4 mon denomination has waves on its reverse making it easily distinguishable from other coins. From 1738 the government authorised the manufacture of iron Kan'ei Tsūhō 1 mon coins, and in 1866 (just before the end of the Edo period ) iron 4 mon Kan'ei Tsūhō were authorised. While iron coins were being minted, the quality of copper coins would decrease due to frequent debasements . As Bitasen coins were no longer allowed to circulate within Japan, Japanese traders started selling them on foreign markets for profits, especially on

1537-495: The Tokugawa shogunate as a means to standardise copper coins and keep up a sufficient supply of copper coinage, being the first government minted copper coin in 700 years, despite this however they were introduced in the Mito domain 10 years prior during the 3rd year of the Kan'ei era. These coins would become the daily currency of the common people and would be used for small payments. Due to

1590-402: The criteria for a medium of exchange cited above. Specifically, prevailing fiat money is free-floating, and depending upon its supply market finds or sets a value to it that continues to change as the supply of money shifts with respect to the economy's demand. Increasing free-floating money supply with respect to needs of the economy reduces the quantity of the basket of the goods and services. It

1643-421: The driving out of the good money entirely. Other functions rely not on recognition of some token or weight of metal in a marketplace, where time to detect any counterfeit is limited and benefits for successful passing-off are high, but on more stable long term social contracts : one cannot easily force a whole society to accept a different standard of deferred payment, require even small groups of people to uphold

Sanzu River - Misplaced Pages Continue

1696-423: The entire system is broken and the whole infrastructure is obsolete – new keys must be re-generated and the new system will also depend on some assumptions about difficulty of factoring. Due to this inherent fragility, which is even more profound with electronic voting , some economists argue that units of account should not ever be abstracted or confused with the nominal units or tokens used in exchange. A medium

1749-566: The fact that coins were very often 'shaved.' Precious metal was removed from them, leaving them still useful as an identifiable coin in the marketplace, for a certain number of units in trade, but which no longer had the quantity of metal supplied by the coin's minter. It was observed as early as Oresme , Copernicus and then in 1558 by Sir Thomas Gresham , that "bad" money drives out "good" in any marketplace; ( Gresham's law states "Where legal tender laws exist, bad money drives out good money"). A more precise definition follows that: "A currency that

1802-565: The form of 100 on Ryūkyū Tsūhō coins and even ½ Shu Ryūkyū Tsūhō coins under the pretence of minting coins for their vassal Ryukyu Kingdom , this proved profitable for the Satsuma domain . Mon coins were holed, allowing them to be strung together on a piece of string. In the Edo period of Japan (1615-1868), stringed together coins received a small discount when presented like this. For example, for 100 Mon payment: if those 1 Mon coins were all tied in

1855-440: The medium of exchange function has become wholly a part of the marketplace and its signals, and is utterly integrated with the unit of account function, so that, given the integrity of the public key system on which these are based, they become to that degree inseparable. This has clear advantages – counterfeiting is difficult or impossible unless the whole system is compromised, say by a new factoring algorithm . But at that point,

1908-514: The mon became invalid: postwar inflation had removed sen, mon etc. denominations smaller than 1 Yen. Due to the missing small coinage, the Japanese posts issued their first stamps (Meiji 4.3.1 / 1871.4.20) in mon and fixed postal rates in mon until April 1872 (Meiji 5.2.28). During the co-existence of the mon with the sen between 1870 and 1891, the metal content of the old currency became important. Official exchange for coins from 1871.6.27: 4 copper mon = 2 rin, 1 bronze mon = 1 rin (1 rin = 1/10 of

1961-401: The most commonly used medium of exchange is currency . Most forms of money are categorised as mediums of exchange, including commodity money , representative money , cryptocurrency , and most commonly fiat money . Representative and fiat money most widely exist in digital form as well as physical tokens, for example coins and notes. The origin of "mediums of exchange" in human societies

2014-419: The nation's money supply expanded by 2.5 times between 1859 and 1869, leading to crumbling money values and soaring prices. These coins were often produced with the name of the domain or province on them. The mon coins produced by domains are: Medium for exchange In economics , a medium of exchange is any item that is widely acceptable in exchange for goods and services. In modern economies,

2067-476: The new fixing officially was set for 1 ryō/yen = 1,000 mon. The yen started to replace the old non-decimal denominations in 1870: in the 3rd quarter of 1870, the first new coins appeared, namely 5, 10, 50 sen silver and 2, 5, 10, 20 Yen. Smaller sen coins did not appear before spring, 1873. So the mon coins (1, 4, 100, 250 mon etc.) remained a necessity for ordinary peoples commodities and were allowed to circulate until 31 December 1891. From January 1, 1954, onward,

2120-457: The other desires. A medium of exchange removes that requirement, allowing an individual to sell and buy from various parties via an intermediary instrument. A barter market theoretically requires a value being known of every commodity, which is both impractical to arrange and impractical to maintain. If all exchanges go 'through' an intermediate medium, such as money, then goods can be priced in terms of that one medium. The medium of exchange allows

2173-513: The people started preferring coinage to barter, leading to a growth of demand for copper coins. The Southern Song dynasty prohibited the export of its coinage in 1179 due to its problem with the outflow of currency, but shiploads of Chinese coins would still enter Japan annually through Ningbo . There is evidence to suggest that the Yuan dynasty used to extensively export Chinese cash coins to Japan for local circulation. The Sinan shipwreck , which

Sanzu River - Misplaced Pages Continue

2226-530: The previously established tri-metallic system. The concurrent circulation of 1, 4, and (heavily debased) 100 mon coins caused for a chaotic reaction from the market, as did widespread circulation of forged coinage. Another major cause for inflation was that from 1859 local Daimyō started minting their own coinage often with high denominations to increase the money supply or to get more gold and silver for their low copper supplies. In 1862 this inspired Daimyō Shimazu Nariakira to produce Tenpō Tsūhō derivatives in

2279-523: The quantifiable notion of "I owe you one unit of something". In this view, money emerged first as credit and only later acquired the functions of a medium of exchange and a store of value. Graeber's criticism partly relies on and follows that made by A. Mitchell Innes in his 1913 article "What is money?". Innes refutes the barter theory of money, by examining historic evidence and showing that early coins never were of consistent value nor of more or less consistent metal content. Therefore, he concludes that sales

2332-426: The relative values of items in the marketplace to be set and adjusted with ease. This is a dimension of the modern fiat money system referred to as a " unit of account ." A barter transaction requires that both objects being bartered be of equivalent value. A medium of exchange is able to be subdivided into small enough units to approximate the value of any good or service. A barter transaction typically happens on

2385-433: The same fiat money then the person purchasing the product or service can focus on the time price and ignore the monetary price. For example, if a person makes $ 5.00 an hour and wants to buy a product that costs $ 20.00 then the time price will be 4 hours and the actual price in fiat money need not be the focus. Although the unit of account must be in some way related to the medium of exchange in use, e.g. ensuring coinage

2438-574: The shogunate outsourced the mintage to regional and local merchants who would cast them at varying weights and sizes, as well as occasionally having local mint marks . By the 1650s 16 private mints were opened for the production of Kan'ei Tsūhō coins all over Japan. Kan'ei Tsūhō produced before 1688 are referred to as "old Kan’ei" and are recognisable by their similar calligraphic styles making them hard to differentiate from one another, meanwhile Kan'ei Tsūhō coins produced after 1688 (or "new Kan’ei" coins) tend to be more diverse in calligraphic styling, and

2491-404: The spot or over a short period of time. Money, on the other hand, also functions as a store of value , until what is wanted becomes available. An ideal medium of exchange is spread throughout the marketplace to allow individuals with exchange potential to buy and sell. When money serves the function of a store of value , as fiat money does, there are conflicting drivers of monetary policy. This

2544-466: The state is considered good money, within that state. So long as that state produces anything of value to others, the medium of exchange has some value, and the currency may also be useful as a standard of deferred payment among others. Of all functions of money, the medium of exchange function has historically been the most problematic due to counterfeiting , the systematic and deliberate creation of bad money with no authorization to do so, leading to

2597-459: The suggestion that money was invented to replace barter . The problem with this version of history, he suggests, is the lack of any supporting evidence. His research indicates that gift economies were common, at least at the beginnings of the first agrarian societies, when humans used elaborate credit systems. Graeber proposes that money as a unit of account was invented the moment when the unquantifiable obligation "I owe you one" transformed into

2650-565: Was a ship from Ningbo to Hakata that sank off the Korean coast in the year 1323, carried some 8,000 strings of cash coins , which weighed about 26,775 kilograms (59,029 lb). Since the trade had begun with Japan, and they received payment in Chinese coins for Japanese goods, they stopped minting their own copper coinage until 1587. The Ashikaga shogunate imported Kōbu Tsūhō ( 洪武通寶 ), Eiraku Tsūhō ( 永樂通寳 ), and Katei Tsūhō ( 嘉靖通寶 ) from

2703-404: Was exploited by forgers and led to a domino effect of bounced checks – a forerunner of the kind of fragility that electronic systems would eventually bring. In the age of electronic money it was, and remains, common to use very long strings of difficult-to-reproduce numbers, generated by encryption methods, to authenticate transactions and commitments as having come from trusted parties. Thus

SECTION 50

#1732901828269

2756-437: Was long popular as a medium of exchange and store of value because it was inert , meaning it was convenient to move due to even small amounts of gold having a considerable and constant value . Some critics of the prevailing system of fiat money argue that fiat money is the root cause of the continuum of economic crises, since it leads to the dominance of fraud, corruption, and manipulation, precisely as it does not satisfy

2809-546: Was minted at the town of Kajiki , while still using the inscription of the Hongwu Emperor of Ming China . Some Shichūsen would also bear the inscriptions of coins from the Song dynasty , although it was not uncommon for many coins to simply be recasts and copies of older Song and Ming dynasty coins in the form of Iutsushi ( 鋳写し ) or by simply adding extra carvings on existing circulating Chinese coins. Bitasen refers to

#268731