Multi-objective optimization or Pareto optimization (also known as multi-objective programming , vector optimization , multicriteria optimization , or multiattribute optimization ) is an area of multiple-criteria decision making that is concerned with mathematical optimization problems involving more than one objective function to be optimized simultaneously. Multi-objective is a type of vector optimization that has been applied in many fields of science, including engineering, economics and logistics where optimal decisions need to be taken in the presence of trade-offs between two or more conflicting objectives. Minimizing cost while maximizing comfort while buying a car, and maximizing performance whilst minimizing fuel consumption and emission of pollutants of a vehicle are examples of multi-objective optimization problems involving two and three objectives, respectively. In practical problems, there can be more than three objectives.
107-454: For a multi-objective optimization problem, it is not guaranteed that a single solution simultaneously optimizes each objective. The objective functions are said to be conflicting. A solution is called nondominated , Pareto optimal, Pareto efficient or noninferior, if none of the objective functions can be improved in value without degrading some of the other objective values. Without additional subjective preference information, there may exist
214-556: A l − ϵ , ∀ i ∈ { 1 , … , k } {\displaystyle z_{i}^{utop}=z_{i}^{ideal}-\epsilon ,\forall i\in \{1,\dots ,k\}} where ϵ > 0 {\displaystyle \epsilon >0} is a small constant, is often defined because of numerical reasons. In economics , many problems involve multiple objectives along with constraints on what combinations of those objectives are attainable. For example, consumer's demand for various goods
321-402: A . Japanese neo- Walrasian economist Takashi Negishi proved that, under certain assumptions, the opposite is also true: for every Pareto-efficient allocation x , there exists a positive vector a such that x maximizes W a . A shorter proof is provided by Hal Varian . The notion of Pareto efficiency has been used in engineering. Given a set of choices and a way of valuing them,
428-561: A lump-sum transfer of wealth. An ineffective distribution of resources in a free market is known as market failure . Given that there is room for improvement, market failure implies Pareto inefficiency. For instance, excessive use of negative commodities (such as drugs and cigarettes) results in expenses to non-smokers as well as early mortality for smokers. Cigarette taxes may help individuals stop smoking while also raising money to address ailments brought on by smoking. A Pareto improvement may be seen, but this does not always imply that
535-617: A total order relation for n > 1 {\displaystyle n>1} which would not always prioritize one target over another target (like the lexicographical order ). In the multi-objective optimization setting, various solutions can be "incomparable" as there is no total order relation to facilitate the comparison f → ( x → ∗ ) ≥ f → ( x → ) {\displaystyle {\vec {f}}({\vec {x}}^{*})\geq {\vec {f}}({\vec {x}})} . Only
642-516: A van Emde Boas tree in place of the balanced binary search tree. These changes to the algorithm speed up its running time to O ( n log log n ) . In any dimension d the problem can be solved in time O ( dn ) by testing all pairs of points for whether one dominates another, and reporting as output the points that are not dominated. However, when d is a constant greater than three, this can be improved to O ( n (log n ) log log n ) . For point sets that are generated randomly, it
749-437: A (possibly infinite) number of Pareto optimal solutions, all of which are considered equally good. Researchers study multi-objective optimization problems from different viewpoints and, thus, there exist different solution philosophies and goals when setting and solving them. The goal may be to find a representative set of Pareto optimal solutions, and/or quantify the trade-offs in satisfying the different objectives, and/or finding
856-442: A , b , c , d , e ) and 6 voters. The voters' approval sets are ( ac , ad , ae , bc , bd , be ) . All five outcomes are PE, so every lottery is ex-post PE. But the lottery selecting c , d , e with probability 1/3 each is not ex-ante PE, since it gives an expected utility of 1/3 to each voter, while the lottery selecting a , b with probability 1/2 each gives an expected utility of 1/2 to each voter. Bayesian efficiency
963-681: A feasible solution that minimizes all objective functions simultaneously. Therefore, attention is paid to Pareto optimal solutions; that is, solutions that cannot be improved in any of the objectives without degrading at least one of the other objectives. In mathematical terms, a feasible solution x 1 ∈ X {\displaystyle x_{1}\in X} is said to (Pareto) dominate another solution x 2 ∈ X {\displaystyle x_{2}\in X} , if A solution x ∗ ∈ X {\displaystyle x^{*}\in X} (and
1070-514: A goal or target value is not specified for any objective here, which makes it different from the Lexicographic Goal Programming method. Scalarizing a multi-objective optimization problem is an a priori method, which means formulating a single-objective optimization problem such that optimal solutions to the single-objective optimization problem are Pareto optimal solutions to the multi-objective optimization problem. In addition, it
1177-556: A hybrid approach consisting of the weighted Tchebycheff and the Normal Boundary Intersection approach. The novel hybrid approach was able to construct a Pareto optimal set for the thermal processing of foods. In 2013, Ganesan et al. carried out the multi-objective optimization of the combined carbon dioxide reforming and partial oxidation of methane. The objective functions were methane conversion, carbon monoxide selectivity, and hydrogen to carbon monoxide ratio. Ganesan used
SECTION 10
#17330922469041284-417: A labor market where the worker's own productivity is known to the worker but not to a potential employer, or a used-car market where the quality of a car is known to the seller but not to the buyer) which results in moral hazard or an adverse selection and a sub-optimal outcome. In such a case, a planner who wishes to improve the situation is unlikely to have access to any information that the participants in
1391-422: A multi-objective optimization problem can be formulated as where the integer k ≥ 2 {\displaystyle k\geq 2} is the number of objectives and the set X {\displaystyle X} is the feasible set of decision vectors, which is typically X ⊆ R n {\displaystyle X\subseteq \mathbb {R} ^{n}} but it depends on
1498-413: A multi-objective optimization problem is bounded by a so-called nadir objective vector z n a d i r {\displaystyle z^{nadir}} and an ideal objective vector z i d e a l {\displaystyle z^{ideal}} , if these are finite. The nadir objective vector is defined as and the ideal objective vector as In other words,
1605-490: A multi-objective optimization problem, considering production time and the ergonomic impact on the human worker as the two objectives considered in the formulation. Their approach used a Mixed-Integer Linear Program to solve the optimization problem for a weighted sum of the two objectives to calculate a set of Pareto optimal solutions. Applying the approach to several manufacturing tasks showed improvements in at least one objective in most tasks and in both objectives in some of
1712-693: A multi-objective optimization problem. Most evolutionary multi-objective optimization (EMO) algorithms apply Pareto-based ranking schemes. Evolutionary algorithms such as the Non-dominated Sorting Genetic Algorithm-II (NSGA-II), its extended version NSGA-III, Strength Pareto Evolutionary Algorithm 2 (SPEA-2) and multiobjective differential evolution variants have become standard approaches, although some schemes based on particle swarm optimization and simulated annealing are significant. The main advantage of evolutionary algorithms, when applied to solve multi-objective optimization problems,
1819-422: A non-quantitative, judgement-based, process for ranking the alternatives and making the policy choice. In finance , a common problem is to choose a portfolio when there are two conflicting objectives — the desire to have the expected value of portfolio returns be as high as possible, and the desire to have risk , often measured by the standard deviation of portfolio returns, be as low as possible. This problem
1926-483: A paper mill can include objectives such as i) minimization of expected variation of those quality parameters from their nominal values, ii) minimization of the expected time of breaks and iii) minimization of the investment cost of storage volumes. Here, the maximum volume of towers is a design variable. This example of optimal design of a paper mill is a simplification of the model used in. Multi-objective design optimization has also been implemented in engineering systems in
2033-629: A pie. The third person does not lose out (even if he does not partake in the pie), hence splitting it in half and giving it to two individuals would be considered Pareto efficient. On a frontier of production possibilities, Pareto efficiency will happen. It is impossible to raise the output of products without decreasing the output of services when an economy is functioning on a basic production potential frontier, such as at point A, B, or C. If multiple sub-goals f i {\displaystyle f_{i}} (with i > 1 {\displaystyle i>1} ) exist, combined into
2140-399: A point set In computational geometry , a point p in a finite set of points S is said to be maximal or non-dominated if there is no other point q in S whose coordinates are all greater than or equal to the corresponding coordinates of p . The maxima of a point set S are all the maximal points of S . The problem of finding all maximal points, sometimes called the problem of
2247-421: A problem is not as straightforward as it is for a conventional single-objective optimization problem. Therefore, different researchers have defined the term "solving a multi-objective optimization problem" in various ways. This section summarizes some of them and the contexts in which they are used. Many methods convert the original problem with multiple objectives into a single-objective optimization problem . This
SECTION 20
#17330922469042354-408: A problem is to use a graph of indifference curves , representing preferences, and a budget constraint, representing the trade-offs that the consumer is faced with. Another example involves the production possibilities frontier , which specifies what combinations of various types of goods can be produced by a society with certain amounts of various resources. The frontier specifies the trade-offs that
2461-423: A rocket's fuel usage and orientation so that it arrives both at a specified place and at a specified time; or one might want to conduct open market operations so that both the inflation rate and the unemployment rate are as close as possible to their desired values. Often such problems are subject to linear equality constraints that prevent all objectives from being simultaneously perfectly met, especially when
2568-418: A set of outputs of goods is Pareto-efficient if there is no feasible re-allocation of productive inputs such that output of one product increases while the outputs of all other goods either increase or remain the same. Besides economics, the notion of Pareto efficiency has also been applied to selecting alternatives in engineering and biology . Each option is first assessed, under multiple criteria, and then
2675-425: A single solution that satisfies the subjective preferences of a human decision maker (DM). Bicriteria optimization denotes the special case in which there are two objective functions. There is a direct relationship between multitask optimization and multi-objective optimization. A multi-objective optimization problem is an optimization problem that involves multiple objective functions. In mathematical terms,
2782-530: A state is Pareto-optimal if there is no alternative state where at least one participant's well-being is higher, and nobody else's well-being is lower. If there is a state change that satisfies this condition, the new state is called a "Pareto improvement". When no Pareto improvements are possible, the state is a "Pareto optimum". In other words, Pareto efficiency is when it is impossible to make one party better off without making another party worse off. This state indicates that resources can no longer be allocated in
2889-416: A subset of options is identified with the property that no other option can categorically outperform the specified option. It is a statement of impossibility of improving one variable without harming other variables in the subject of multi-objective optimization (also termed Pareto optimization ). The concept is named after Vilfredo Pareto (1848–1923), an Italian civil engineer and economist , who used
2996-402: A subsidy of ten dollars, and nothing otherwise". If there exists no allowed rule that can successfully improve upon the market outcome, then that outcome is said to be "constrained Pareto-optimal". Fractional Pareto efficiency is a strengthening of Pareto efficiency in the context of fair item allocation . An allocation of indivisible items is fractionally Pareto-efficient (fPE or fPO) if it
3103-413: A vector-valued objective function f → = ( f 1 , … f n ) T {\displaystyle {\vec {f}}=(f_{1},\dots f_{n})^{T}} , generally, finding a unique optimum x → ∗ {\displaystyle {\vec {x}}^{*}} becomes challenging. This is due to the absence of
3210-402: A way that makes one party better off without harming other parties. In a state of Pareto Efficiency, resources are allocated in the most efficient way possible. Pareto efficiency is mathematically represented when there is no other strategy profile s' such that u i (s') ≥ u i (s) for every player i and u j (s') > u j (s) for some player j . In this equation s represents
3317-1002: Is Pareto-optimal if there is no other feasible allocation { x 1 ′ , … , x n ′ } {\displaystyle \{x_{1}',\dots ,x_{n}'\}} where, for utility function u i {\displaystyle u_{i}} for each agent i {\displaystyle i} , u i ( x i ′ ) ≥ u i ( x i ) {\displaystyle u_{i}(x_{i}')\geq u_{i}(x_{i})} for all i ∈ { 1 , … , n } {\displaystyle i\in \{1,\dots ,n\}} with u i ( x i ′ ) > u i ( x i ) {\displaystyle u_{i}(x_{i}')>u_{i}(x_{i})} for some i {\displaystyle i} . Here, in this simple economy, "feasibility" refers to an allocation where
Multi-objective optimization - Misplaced Pages Continue
3424-631: Is Pareto-efficient. In zero-sum games , every outcome is Pareto-efficient. A special case of a state is an allocation of resources. The formal presentation of the concept in an economy is the following: Consider an economy with n {\displaystyle n} agents and k {\displaystyle k} goods. Then an allocation { x 1 , … , x n } {\displaystyle \{x_{1},\dots ,x_{n}\}} , where x i ∈ R k {\displaystyle x_{i}\in \mathbb {R} ^{k}} for all i ,
3531-598: Is a pie and three persons; the most equitable way would be to divide the pie into three equal portions. However, if the pie is divided in half and shared between two people, it is considered Pareto efficient – meaning that the third person does not lose out (despite the fact that he does not receive a piece of the pie). When making judgments, it is critical to consider a variety of aspects, including social efficiency, overall welfare, and issues such as diminishing marginal value. In order to fully understand market failure, one must first comprehend market success, which
3638-462: Is a set depending on the parameter θ {\displaystyle \theta } , and g : R k + 1 → R {\displaystyle g:\mathbb {R} ^{k+1}\rightarrow \mathbb {R} } is a function. Very well-known examples are: Somewhat more advanced examples are the following: For example, portfolio optimization is often conducted in terms of mean-variance analysis . In this context,
3745-436: Is a situation that cannot be strictly improved for every individual. Formally, a strong Pareto improvement is defined as a situation in which all agents are strictly better-off (in contrast to just "Pareto improvement", which requires that one agent is strictly better-off and the other agents are at least as good). A situation is weak Pareto-efficient if it has no strong Pareto improvements. Any strong Pareto improvement
3852-414: Is a strict partial order , though it is not a product order (neither non-strict nor strict). If f → ( x → 1 ) ≺ f → ( x → 2 ) {\displaystyle {\vec {f}}({\vec {x}}_{1})\prec {\vec {f}}({\vec {x}}_{2})} , then this defines a preorder in
3959-410: Is a weakening of Pareto optimality, accounting for the fact that a potential planner (e.g., the government) may not be able to improve upon a decentralized market outcome, even if that outcome is inefficient. This will occur if it is limited by the same informational or institutional constraints as are individual agents. An example is of a setting where individuals have private information (for example,
4066-416: Is also a weak Pareto improvement. The opposite is not true; for example, consider a resource allocation problem with two resources, which Alice values at {10, 0}, and George values at {5, 5}. Consider the allocation giving all resources to Alice, where the utility profile is (10, 0): A market does not require local nonsatiation to get to a weak Pareto optimum. Constrained Pareto efficiency
4173-405: Is an adaptation of Pareto efficiency to settings in which players have incomplete information regarding the types of other players. Ordinal Pareto efficiency is an adaptation of Pareto efficiency to settings in which players report only rankings on individual items, and we do not know for sure how they rank entire bundles. Although an outcome may be a Pareto improvement, this does not imply that
4280-414: Is assigned a positive weight a i . For every allocation x , define the welfare of x as the weighted sum of utilities of all agents in x : Let x a be an allocation that maximizes the welfare over all allocations: It is easy to show that the allocation x a is Pareto-efficient: since all weights are positive, any Pareto improvement would increase the sum, contradicting the definition of x
4387-449: Is called a two-moment decision model . In engineering and economics , many problems involve multiple objectives which are not describable as the-more-the-better or the-less-the-better; instead, there is an ideal target value for each objective, and the desire is to get as close as possible to the desired value of each objective. For example, energy systems typically have a trade-off between performance and cost or one might want to adjust
Multi-objective optimization - Misplaced Pages Continue
4494-482: Is called a scalarized problem. If the Pareto optimality of the single-objective solutions obtained can be guaranteed, the scalarization is characterized as done neatly. Solving a multi-objective optimization problem is sometimes understood as approximating or computing all or a representative set of Pareto optimal solutions. When decision making is emphasized, the objective of solving a multi-objective optimization problem
4601-422: Is defined as an inefficient allocation of resources. Due to the fact that it is feasible to improve, market failure implies Pareto inefficiency. For example, excessive consumption of depreciating items (drugs/tobacco) results in external costs to non-smokers, as well as premature death for smokers who do not quit. An increase in the price of cigarettes could motivate people to quit smoking while also raising funds for
4708-427: Is defined as the ability of a set of idealized competitive markets to achieve an equilibrium allocation of resources that is Pareto-optimal in terms of resource allocation. According to the definition of market failure, it is a circumstance in which the conclusion of the first fundamental theorem of welfare is erroneous; that is, when the allocations made through markets are not efficient. In a free market, market failure
4815-469: Is determined by the process of maximization of the utilities derived from those goods, subject to a constraint based on how much income is available to spend on those goods and on the prices of those goods. This constraint allows more of one good to be purchased only at the sacrifice of consuming less of another good; therefore, the various objectives (more consumption of each good is preferred) are in conflict with each other. A common method for analyzing such
4922-408: Is not Pareto-dominated even by an allocation in which some items are split between agents. This is in contrast to standard Pareto efficiency, which only considers domination by feasible (discrete) allocations. As an example, consider an item allocation problem with two items, which Alice values at {3, 2} and George values at {4, 1}. Consider the allocation giving the first item to Alice and
5029-470: Is not feasible, and generating an inspection plan may be better viewed as a multiobjective optimization problem, where one aims to both maximize inspection coverage and minimize time and costs. A recent study has indicated that multiobjective inspection planning indeed has the potential to outperform traditional methods on complex structures As multiple Pareto optimal solutions for multi-objective optimization problems usually exist, what it means to solve such
5136-476: Is not true: ex-ante PE is stronger that ex-post PE. For example, suppose there are two objects – a car and a house. Alice values the car at 2 and the house at 3; George values the car at 2 and the house at 9. Consider the following two lotteries: While both lotteries are ex-post PE, the lottery 1 is not ex-ante PE, since it is Pareto-dominated by lottery 2. Another example involves dichotomous preferences . There are 5 possible outcomes (
5243-419: Is often represented by a graph in which the efficient frontier shows the best combinations of risk and expected return that are available, and in which indifference curves show the investor's preferences for various risk-expected return combinations. The problem of optimizing a function of the expected value (first moment ) and the standard deviation (square root of the second central moment) of portfolio return
5350-492: Is often required that every Pareto optimal solution can be reached with some parameters of the scalarization. With different parameters for the scalarization, different Pareto optimal solutions are produced. A general formulation for a scalarization of a multi-objective optimization problem is where θ {\displaystyle \theta } is a vector parameter, the set X θ ⊆ X {\displaystyle X_{\theta }\subseteq X}
5457-612: Is possible to solve the problem in linear time . Pareto optimality In welfare economics , a Pareto improvement formalizes the idea of an outcome being "better in every possible way". A change is called a Pareto improvement if it leaves everyone in a society better-off (or at least as well-off as they were before). A situation is called Pareto efficient or Pareto optimal if all possible Pareto improvements have already been made; in other words, there are no longer any ways left to make one person better-off, without making some other person worse-off. In social choice theory ,
SECTION 50
#17330922469045564-572: Is referred to as supporting a decision maker in finding the most preferred Pareto optimal solution according to their subjective preferences. The underlying assumption is that one solution to the problem must be identified to be implemented in practice. Here, a human decision maker (DM) plays an important role. The DM is expected to be an expert in the problem domain. The most preferred results can be found using different philosophies. Multi-objective optimization methods can be divided into four classes. More information and examples of different methods in
5671-421: Is sensitive to the scaling of the objective functions. Thus, it is recommended that the objectives be normalized into a uniform, dimensionless scale. A priori methods require that sufficient preference information is expressed before the solution process. Well-known examples of a priori methods include the utility function method, lexicographic method, and goal programming . The utility function method assumes
5778-399: Is the Pareto order. This means that y → ( 1 ) {\displaystyle {\vec {y}}^{(1)}} is not worse than y → ( 2 ) {\displaystyle {\vec {y}}^{(2)}} in any goal but is better (since smaller) in at least one goal j {\displaystyle j} . The Pareto order
5885-441: Is the fact that they typically generate sets of solutions, allowing computation of an approximation of the entire Pareto front. The main disadvantage of evolutionary algorithms is their lower speed and the Pareto optimality of the solutions cannot be guaranteed; it is only known that none of the generated solutions is dominated by another. Another paradigm for multi-objective optimization based on novelty using evolutionary algorithms
5992-435: The n {\displaystyle n} -dimensional application domain. The feasible set is typically defined by some constraint functions. In addition, the vector-valued objective function is often defined as If some objective function is to be maximized, it is equivalent to minimize its negative or its inverse. We denote Y ⊆ R k {\displaystyle Y\subseteq \mathbb {R} ^{k}}
6099-552: The Pareto front (or Pareto set or Pareto frontier ) is the set of choices that are Pareto-efficient. By restricting attention to the set of choices that are Pareto-efficient, a designer can make trade-offs within this set, rather than considering the full range of every parameter. Modern microeconomic theory has drawn heavily upon the concept of Pareto efficiency for inspiration. Pareto and his successors have tended to describe this technical definition of optimal resource allocation in
6206-419: The first welfare theorem , a competitive market leads to a Pareto-efficient outcome. This result was first demonstrated mathematically by economists Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu . However, the result only holds under the assumptions of the theorem: markets exist for all possible goods, there are no externalities , markets are perfectly competitive, and market participants have perfect information . In
6313-584: The minimax principle, where always the worst of the different objectives is optimized. A posteriori methods aim at producing all the Pareto optimal solutions or a representative subset of the Pareto optimal solutions. Most a posteriori methods fall into either one of the following three classes: Well-known examples of mathematical programming-based a posteriori methods are the Normal Boundary Intersection (NBI), Modified Normal Boundary Intersection (NBIm), Normal Constraint (NC), Successive Pareto Optimization (SPO), and Directed Search Domain (DSD) methods, which solve
6420-586: The Adaptive Random Search Algorithm, and the Penalty Functions Approach were used to compute the initial set of the non-dominated or Pareto-optimal solutions. The Analytic Hierarchy Process and Tabular Method were used simultaneously for choosing the best alternative among the computed subset of non-dominated solutions for osmotic dehydration processes. In 2018, Pearce et al. formulated task allocation to human and robotic workers as
6527-489: The Normal Boundary Intersection (NBI) method in conjunction with two swarm-based techniques (Gravitational Search Algorithm (GSA) and Particle Swarm Optimization (PSO)) to tackle the problem. Applications involving chemical extraction and bioethanol production processes have posed similar multi-objective problems. In 2013, Abakarov et al. proposed an alternative technique to solve multi-objective optimization problems arising in food engineering. The Aggregating Functions Approach,
SECTION 60
#17330922469046634-1351: The Pareto order is applicable: Consider a vector-valued minimization problem: y → ( 1 ) ∈ R n {\displaystyle {\vec {y}}^{(1)}\in \mathbb {R} ^{n}} Pareto dominates y → ( 2 ) ∈ R n {\displaystyle {\vec {y}}^{(2)}\in \mathbb {R} ^{n}} if and only if: : ∀ i ∈ 1 , … m : y → i ( 1 ) ≤ y → i ( 2 ) {\displaystyle \forall i\in {1,\dots m}:{\vec {y}}_{i}^{(1)}\leq {\vec {y}}_{i}^{(2)}} and ∃ j ∈ 1 , … m : y → j ( 1 ) < y → j ( 2 ) . {\displaystyle \exists j\in {1,\dots m}:{\vec {y}}_{j}^{(1)}<{\vec {y}}_{j}^{(2)}.} We then write y → ( 1 ) ≺ y → ( 2 ) {\displaystyle {\vec {y}}^{(1)}\prec {\vec {y}}^{(2)}} , where ≺ {\displaystyle \prec }
6741-462: The absence of perfect information or complete markets, outcomes will generally be Pareto-inefficient, per the Greenwald–Stiglitz theorem . The second welfare theorem is essentially the reverse of the first welfare theorem. It states that under similar, ideal assumptions, any Pareto optimum can be obtained by some competitive equilibrium , or free market system, although it may also require
6848-455: The central bank uses a model of the economy that quantitatively describes the various causal linkages in the economy; it simulates the model repeatedly under various possible stances of monetary policy, in order to obtain a menu of possible predicted outcomes for the various variables of interest. Then in principle it can use an aggregate objective function to rate the alternative sets of predicted outcomes, although in practice central banks use
6955-459: The circumstances such as control cabinet layout optimization, airfoil shape optimization using scientific workflows, design of nano- CMOS , system on chip design, design of solar-powered irrigation systems, optimization of sand mould systems, engine design, optimal sensor deployment and optimal controller design. Multi-objective optimization has been increasingly employed in chemical engineering and manufacturing . In 2009, Fiandaca and Fraga used
7062-438: The common utility of weighted sum rate gives an NP-hard problem with a complexity that scales exponentially with the number of users, while the weighted max-min fairness utility results in a quasi-convex optimization problem with only a polynomial scaling with the number of users. Reconfiguration, by exchanging the functional links between the elements of the system, represents one of the most important measures which can improve
7169-487: The components of the nadir and ideal objective vectors define the upper and lower bounds of the objective function of Pareto optimal solutions. In practice, the nadir objective vector can only be approximated as, typically, the whole Pareto optimal set is unknown. In addition, a utopian objective vector z u t o p {\displaystyle z^{utop}} , such that z i u t o p = z i i d e
7276-427: The concept in his studies of economic efficiency and income distribution . Pareto originally used the word "optimal" for the concept, but this is somewhat of a misnomer : Pareto's concept more closely aligns with an idea of "efficiency", because it does not identify a single "best" (optimal) outcome. Instead, it only identifies a set of outcomes that might be considered optimal, by at least one person. Formally,
7383-592: The context of it being an equilibrium that can theoretically be achieved within an abstract model of market competition. It has therefore very often been treated as a corroboration of Adam Smith 's " invisible hand " notion. More specifically, it motivated the debate over " market socialism " in the 1930s. However, because the Pareto-efficient outcome is difficult to assess in the real world when issues including asymmetric information, signalling, adverse selection, and moral hazard are introduced, most people do not take
7490-413: The corresponding outcome f ( x ∗ ) {\displaystyle f(x^{*})} ) is called Pareto optimal if there does not exist another solution that dominates it. The set of Pareto optimal outcomes, denoted X ∗ {\displaystyle X^{*}} , is often called the Pareto front , Pareto frontier, or Pareto boundary. The Pareto front of
7597-600: The decision maker prefers y 1 {\displaystyle \mathbf {y} ^{1}} to y 2 {\displaystyle \mathbf {y} ^{2}} , and u ( y 1 ) = u ( y 2 ) {\displaystyle u(\mathbf {y} ^{1})=u(\mathbf {y} ^{2})} if the decision maker is indifferent between y 1 {\displaystyle \mathbf {y} ^{1}} and y 2 {\displaystyle \mathbf {y} ^{2}} . The utility function specifies an ordering of
7704-584: The decision maker's utility function is available. A mapping u : Y → R {\displaystyle u\colon Y\rightarrow \mathbb {R} } is a utility function if for all y 1 , y 2 ∈ Y {\displaystyle \mathbf {y} ^{1},\mathbf {y} ^{2}\in Y} it holds that u ( y 1 ) > u ( y 2 ) {\displaystyle u(\mathbf {y} ^{1})>u(\mathbf {y} ^{2})} if
7811-423: The decision vectors (recall that vectors can be ordered in many different ways). Once u {\displaystyle u} is obtained, it suffices to solve but in practice, it is very difficult to construct a utility function that would accurately represent the decision maker's preferences, particularly since the Pareto front is unknown before the optimization begins. The lexicographic method assumes that
7918-435: The definition above, let s = (-2, -2) ( Both Defect ) and s' = (-1, -1) ( Both Cooperate ). Then u i (s') > u i (s) for all i . Thus Both Cooperate is a Pareto improvement over Both Defect , which means that Both Defect is not Pareto-efficient. Furthermore, neither of the remaining strategy profiles, (0, -5) or (-5, 0) , is a Pareto improvement over Both Cooperate , since -5 < -1 . Thus Both Cooperate
8025-413: The efficient set can be specified by choosing the portfolio shares to maximize the function μ P − b σ P {\displaystyle \mu _{P}-b\sigma _{P}} ; the set of efficient portfolios consists of the solutions as b {\displaystyle b} ranges from zero to infinity. Some of the above scalarizations involve invoking
8132-499: The efficient set is a subset of the portfolios parametrized by the portfolio mean return μ P {\displaystyle \mu _{P}} in the problem of choosing portfolio shares to minimize the portfolio's variance of return σ P {\displaystyle \sigma _{P}} subject to a given value of μ P {\displaystyle \mu _{P}} ; see Mutual fund separation theorem for details. Alternatively,
8239-451: The existing points, to find and remove the previously-undominated points that are dominated by a new point, and to add a new point to the set of maximal points, in logarithmic time per point. The number of search tree operations is linear over the course of the algorithm, so the total time is O ( n log n ) . For points with integer coordinates the first part of the algorithm, sorting the points, can again be sped up by integer sorting. If
8346-432: The following steps: If the coordinates of the points are assumed to be integers , this can be sped up using integer sorting algorithms, to have the same asymptotic running time as the sorting algorithms. For points in three dimensions, it is again possible to find the maximal points in time O ( n log n ) using an algorithm similar to the two-dimensional one that performs the following steps: This method reduces
8453-796: The four classes are given in the following sections. When a decision maker does not explicitly articulate any preference information, the multi-objective optimization method can be classified as a no-preference method. A well-known example is the method of global criterion, in which a scalarized problem of the form is solved. In the above problem, ‖ ⋅ ‖ {\displaystyle \|\cdot \|} can be any L p {\displaystyle L_{p}} norm , with common choices including L 1 {\displaystyle L_{1}} , L 2 {\displaystyle L_{2}} , and L ∞ {\displaystyle L_{\infty }} . The method of global criterion
8560-427: The frequency resources are very scarce, thus there is a need for tight spatial frequency reuse which causes immense inter-user interference if not properly controlled. Multi-user MIMO techniques are nowadays used to reduce the interference by adaptive precoding . The network operator would like to both bring great coverage and high data rates, thus the operator would like to find a Pareto optimal solution that balance
8667-488: The image of X {\displaystyle X} ; x ∗ ∈ X {\displaystyle x^{*}\in X} a feasible solution or feasible decision ; and z ∗ = f ( x ∗ ) ∈ R k {\displaystyle z^{*}=f(x^{*})\in \mathbb {R} ^{k}} an objective vector or an outcome . In multi-objective optimization, there does not typically exist
8774-467: The markets do not have. Hence, the planner cannot implement allocation rules which are based on the idiosyncratic characteristics of individuals; for example, "if a person is of type A , they pay price p 1 , but if of type B , they pay price p 2 " (see Lindahl prices ). Essentially, only anonymous rules are allowed (of the sort "Everyone pays price p ") or rules based on observable behavior; "if any person chooses x at price p x , then they get
8881-563: The maxima or maxima set problem , has been studied as a variant of the convex hull and orthogonal convex hull problems. It is equivalent to finding the Pareto frontier of a collection of points, and was called the floating-currency problem by Herbert Freeman based on an application involving comparing the relative wealth of individuals with different holdings of multiple currencies. For points in two dimensions, this problem can be solved in time O ( n log n ) by an algorithm that performs
8988-526: The multi-objective genetic algorithm (MOGA) to optimize the pressure swing adsorption process (cyclic separation process). The design problem involved the dual maximization of nitrogen recovery and nitrogen purity. The results approximated the Pareto frontier well with acceptable trade-offs between the objectives. In 2010, Sendín et al. solved a multi-objective problem for the thermal processing of food. They tackled two case studies (bi-objective and triple-objective problems) with nonlinear dynamic models. They used
9095-498: The multi-objective optimization problem by constructing several scalarizations. The solution to each scalarization yields a Pareto optimal solution, whether locally or globally. The scalarizations of the NBI, NBIm, NC, and DSD methods are constructed to obtain evenly distributed Pareto points that give a good approximation of the real set of Pareto points. Evolutionary algorithms are popular approaches to generating Pareto optimal solutions to
9202-442: The number of controllable variables is less than the number of objectives and when the presence of random shocks generates uncertainty. Commonly a multi-objective quadratic objective function is used, with the cost associated with an objective rising quadratically with the distance of the objective from its ideal value. Since these problems typically involve adjusting the controlled variables at various points in time and/or evaluating
9309-410: The objectives at various points in time, intertemporal optimization techniques are employed. Product and process design can be largely improved using modern modeling, simulation, and optimization techniques. The key question in optimal design is measuring what is good or desirable about a design. Before looking for optimal designs, it is important to identify characteristics that contribute the most to
9416-445: The objectives can be ranked in the order of importance. We assume that the objective functions are in the order of importance so that f 1 {\displaystyle f_{1}} is the most important and f k {\displaystyle f_{k}} the least important to the decision maker. Subject to this assumption, various methods can be used to attain the lexicographically optimal solution. Note that
9523-445: The operational performance of a distribution system. The problem of optimization through the reconfiguration of a power distribution system, in terms of its definition, is a historical single objective problem with constraints. Since 1975, when Merlin and Back introduced the idea of distribution system reconfiguration for active power loss reduction, until nowadays, a lot of researchers have proposed diverse methods and algorithms to solve
9630-408: The optimal value for one objective requires some compromise on one or more objectives. For example, when designing a paper mill, one can seek to decrease the amount of capital invested in a paper mill and enhance the quality of paper simultaneously. If the design of a paper mill is defined by large storage volumes and paper quality is defined by quality parameters, then the problem of optimal design of
9737-412: The outcome is equitable. It is possible that inequality persists even after a Pareto improvement. Despite the fact that it is frequently used in conjunction with the idea of Pareto optimality, the term "efficiency" refers to the process of increasing societal productivity. It is possible for a society to have Pareto efficiency while also have high levels of inequality. Consider the following scenario: there
9844-432: The overall value of the design. A good design typically involves multiple criteria/objectives such as capital cost/investment, operating cost, profit, quality and/or product recovery, efficiency, process safety, operation time, etc. Therefore, in practical applications, the performance of process and product design is often measured with respect to multiple objectives. These objectives are typically conflicting, i.e., achieving
9951-413: The points are sorted separately by all three of their dimensions, the range of values of their coordinates can be reduced to the range from 1 to n without changing the relative order of any two coordinates and without changing the identities of the maximal points. After this reduction in the coordinate space, the problem of maintaining a dynamic two-dimensional set of maximal points may be solved by using
10058-403: The potential to reduce costs, risks and environmental impacts, as well as ensuring better periodic maintenance of inspected assets. Typically, planning such missions has been viewed as a single-objective optimization problem, where one aims to minimize the energy or time spent in inspecting an entire target structure. For complex, real-world structures, however, covering 100% of an inspection target
10165-402: The problem of computing the maximal points of a static three-dimensional point set to one of maintaining the maximal points of a dynamic two-dimensional point set. The two-dimensional subproblem can be solved efficiently by using a balanced binary search tree to maintain the set of maxima of a dynamic point set. Using this data structure, it is possible to test whether a new point is dominated by
10272-401: The processes. The purpose of radio resource management is to satisfy the data rates that are requested by the users of a cellular network. The main resources are time intervals, frequency blocks, and transmit powers. Each user has its own objective function that, for example, can represent some combination of the data rate, latency, and energy efficiency. These objectives are conflicting since
10379-424: The reconfiguration problem as a single objective problem. Some authors have proposed Pareto optimality based approaches (including active power losses and reliability indices as objectives). For this purpose, different artificial intelligence based methods have been used: microgenetic, branch exchange, particle swarm optimization and non-dominated sorting genetic algorithm. Autonomous inspection of infrastructure has
10486-421: The result is desirable or equitable. After a Pareto improvement, inequality could still exist. However, it does imply that any change will violate the "do no harm" principle, because at least one person will be worse off. A society may be Pareto efficient but have significant levels of inequality. The most equitable course of action would be to split the pie into three equal portions if there were three persons and
10593-433: The same concept is sometimes called the unanimity principle , which says that if everyone in a society ( non-strictly ) prefers A to B, society as a whole also non-strictly prefers A to B. The Pareto front consists of all Pareto-efficient situations. In addition to the context of efficiency in allocation , the concept of Pareto efficiency also arises in the context of efficiency in production vs. x-inefficiency :
10700-512: The search space and we say x → 1 {\displaystyle {\vec {x}}_{1}} Pareto dominates the alternative x → 2 {\displaystyle {\vec {x}}_{2}} and we write x → 1 ≺ f → x → 2 {\displaystyle {\vec {x}}_{1}\prec _{\vec {f}}{\vec {x}}_{2}} . Weak Pareto efficiency
10807-587: The second to George, where the utility profile is (3, 1): When the decision process is random, such as in fair random assignment or random social choice or fractional approval voting , there is a difference between ex-post and ex-ante Pareto efficiency : If some lottery L is ex-ante PE, then it is also ex-post PE. Proof : suppose that one of the ex-post outcomes x of L is Pareto-dominated by some other outcome y . Then, by moving some probability mass from x to y , one attains another lottery L ' that ex-ante Pareto-dominates L . The opposite
10914-530: The society is faced with — if the society is fully utilizing its resources, more of one good can be produced only at the expense of producing less of another good. A society must then use some process to choose among the possibilities on the frontier. Macroeconomic policy -making is a context requiring multi-objective optimization. Typically a central bank must choose a stance for monetary policy that balances competing objectives — low inflation , low unemployment , low balance of trade deficit, etc. To do this,
11021-425: The strategy profile, u represents the utility or benefit, and j represents the player. Efficiency is an important criterion for judging behavior in a game. In a notable and often analyzed game known as Prisoner's Dilemma , depicted below as a normal-form game , this concept of efficiency can be observed, in that the strategy profile ( Cooperate , Cooperate ) is more efficient than ( Defect , Defect ). Using
11128-406: The total amount of each good that is allocated sums to no more than the total amount of the good in the economy. In a more complex economy with production, an allocation would consist both of consumption vectors and production vectors, and feasibility would require that the total amount of each consumed good is no greater than the initial endowment plus the amount produced. Under the assumptions of
11235-406: The total network data throughput and the user fairness in an appropriate subjective manner. Radio resource management is often solved by scalarization; that is, selection of a network utility function that tries to balance throughput and user fairness. The choice of utility function has a large impact on the computational complexity of the resulting single-objective optimization problem. For example,
11342-404: The treatment of smoking-related ailments. Given some ε > 0, an outcome is called ε -Pareto-efficient if no other outcome gives all agents at least the same utility, and one agent a utility at least (1 + ε ) higher. This captures the notion that improvements smaller than (1 + ε ) are negligible and should not be considered a breach of efficiency. Suppose each agent i
11449-424: Was recently improved upon. This paradigm searches for novel solutions in objective space (i.e., novelty search on objective space) in addition to the search for non-dominated solutions. Novelty search is like stepping stones guiding the search to previously unexplored places. It is especially useful in overcoming bias and plateaus as well as guiding the search in many-objective optimization problems. Maxima of
#903096